Showing posts with label Viscusi. Show all posts
Showing posts with label Viscusi. Show all posts

Tuesday, 21 January 2014

Day 201: Proving the existence of rational smoking

At the beginning of the week, before Kip Viscusi began his testimony at the Montreal tobacco trials, my colleague Pierre leaned over to share a joke about economists.
Why is economics a theology and not a science? 
Because if it were a science, they would have tried it on animals first.

Mr. Viscusi's second and last day of testimony was given over to his cross-examination by plaintiff lawyers André Lespérance and Philippe Trudel. It often resembled a theological debate. 

This impression of religion-over-science was only somewhat aided by the church-like structure of the courtroom, with its centre aisle and the bar dividing onlookers in the nave from the officiants in the chancel. The medieval clerical robes worn by lawyers and judge didn't hurt either.

What really gave it the air of a debate among Jesuits was philosophical thrust of the questions thrown at Mr. Viscusi, and his apparent willingness to have all facts serve to prove, if not the existence of God, then at least the infallibility of the consumer market. 

For someone who was being put through the epistemological wringer, Mr. Viscusi looked not too bad at the end of the day. He kept to his script and kept his composure. But his conclusions looked considerably the worse for the exercise, with the stuffing knocked out of some of his core assertions. 

Act global. Be fuzzy on the local.

One of the more awkward moments for Mr. Viscusi came late morning, when Mr. Trudel began his round of questions with a focus on when Mr. Viscusi had been engaged, what he had been hired to do and who had been his contact.

Again, this witness seemed unrealistically unable to provide details about his activities. Yesterday's statement that he had testified for "10 to 15" trials was a more precise answer than he seemed able to muster for questions about the process of writing this report less than a year ago.

He wasn't sure when he had first been approached. He wasn't sure if he had received a written mandate from the companies. He seemed unsure of who had framed the questions he would answer until it became clear during discussions that it would be better for his clients if it were lawyers who had done so. At that point he remembered that in fact it was the lawyers.

He knew he had been contacted by John Blain of Freshfields, but wasn't sure which company Mr. Blain represented. (Freshfields is based in the United Kingdom. It's client is JTI-International. Mr. Blain has been previously spotted in this court, during the first appearance of Mr. Hoult). "I don't keep track of clients," Mr. Viscusi said.  

Several times he was unable to say why or how certain documents were included or excluded from his review. Some came from the report presented by Raymond Duch last year, others (like findings from Imperial Tobacco's Viking report) seemed to have appeared in other work prepared by Mr. Duch.

Court rules mandate that source material for expert reports be shared with opponents - so the fact that Mr. Viscusi could not recall how he received source material, or what he might have done with it was significant. Even more fishy-sounding was his explanation that he destroyed all the electronic records that were provided to him by the lawyers. He said this was because he was not allowed to keep too much material on his laptop, and had a "modest allotment in terms of what we are allowed to keep on our computers" by his university. You could almost hear his credibility bang down a few notches with that comment. 

Unravelling the knotted arguments

Although it is padded with many comments on the way people respond to risk communication, the core of Mr. Viscusi's expert report (Exhibit 40494) is a tightly bound theory.

Smokers make rational decisions to smoke. They make these decisions based on their perceptions of risk and benefit. Their perceptions of the risks of smoking are much greater than the true risks. Giving them more information about the risks of smoking would actually reduce their perceptions of risk and would therefore lead to more smoking. 

Mr. Lespérance and then Mr. Trudel challenged this theory by poking at its assumptions and embedded components, and showing where these were inconsistent with other evidence at this trial. Do smokers over-estimate the risks of smoking? Are Mr. Viscusi's statements of the "true risks" accurate? Do smokers really not benefit from warnings? 

They also challenged the credibility of the man by asking questions that exposed his unwillingness to provide frank answers about the events that brought him to this courtroom, and about issues that were excluded from his report.

At times, the exchanges were tense and intense - the questions put with incremental forcefulness and a witness who frequently feigned misunderstanding. More than a few times, it was only after Justice Riordan repeated questions that Mr. Viscusi responded. His squirming away from answers may have left a more lasting impression than the answers he gave.

The few occasions that Mr. Pratte intervened with objections provoked uncharacteristic rebukes from Justice Riordan, who spoke more harshly against "talking objections" than he previously has. (Such objections are disguised hints to the witness).

Do smokers over-estimate the risks of smoking? 

Mr. Lespérance showed Mr. Viscusi measurements of smokers' perceptions of the risks of smoking, including some that were undertaken for Imperial Tobacco. (Exhibits 987.12, 987.6, 1547.1, 40064.61). 

These reports have been much talked about at this trial, but it would appear that no-one informed Mr. Viscusi of them. This lack of familiarity did not stop him from quickly identifying methodological flaws that would explain why all this research on Canadian attitudes and beliefs came to different conclusions than his own.

Mr. Viscusi acknowledges that every cigarette smoked presents a risk - "there is no level of smoking that proses zero risk to all risks." But the finding from Imperial Tobacco's long-running survey that 80% of smokers thought it was possible to smoke three or more cigarettes without risk did not suggest that smokers underestimated this danger. The question was flawed - it was not "probabilistic."

Similarly, the finding that fewer than half of respondents believed that smokers died at a younger age than non-smokers was invalid in his view. It was a "badly worded question – it should be worded, like my questions, in terms of life expectancy."

A 1990 Environics report which showed smokers unable to state many of the diseases caused by smoking was criticized for being an open-ended question format. "That's different than taking people through laundry list. People say one or two things to get the surveyor off their back. It doesn't  mean that people are not aware of the risks, it just means they didn’t bother to mention them." 

Imperial Tobacco's surveys found that smokers believed that they only risked losing a couple of life years to smoking. (Exhibit 987.21) Again, he found fault with the survey methods. "This is not a reliable way to ascertain life expectancy." 

Did Mr. Viscusi underestimate the real risk of smoking?

The fundamental  underpinning of Mr. Viscusi's argument is that health authorities place a lower risk on smoking than smokers do. He cites the Surgeon General as the source of the "true estimate" that between one-sixth and one-third of smokers die as a result of tobacco use, and the Institutes of Medicine that the average smoker actually loses 6.6 years of life. 

He struggled, however, to remember exactly how he got those numbers, or to produce the exact sources from the American authorities. He had a much clearer memory of the flaws of other researchers who reached different conclusions. These included the conclusions of Doll, Peto and others who concluded that one-half of smokers died from tobacco use, and those who did lost an average of 15 years of life. (Exhibit 1545, 977)

Addiction and the rational decision to smoke.

Mr. Viscusi's report does not talk about smokers' knowledge of addiction, or the potential impact of warnings in this area. Given that the Létourneau half of this joint-trial is solely about addiction, it was a curious oversight.

To Mr. Lespérance's questions of why it was excluded, Mr. Viscusi explained that he "did not know it was part of the case."  Moreover, it was not "not a probability of health outcome – it is a property of cigarettes."
He agreed that smoking was addictive -- but that this only happened after 1988, when the Surgeon General labelled it so. He was unwilling to state whether addiction itself could be considered a disease -- only, he said "if it is something that caused death… if addiction to cigarettes independent of any other risks killed you, it would be included."  

Addiction does not seem to figure prominently in his model of the rational decision to smoke. This decision, he says, is made every time a smoker lights up. Addiction plays a role in so far as it increases the costs of quitting. In these cases, the smoker makes "a rational decision that you are not willing to put up the costs of giving up compared with the benefits."
Against these costs the smoker would consider the benefits, and Mr. Viscusi acknowledges that "nicotine is one of the benefits of smoking to smokers." He resisted the use of the term "fix,"  and bristled at comparisons between heroin and nicotine. 
He also resisted the idea that smokers might "lose control". When shown the ruling of the Supreme Court in the Insite decision that supported the understanding that "addiction is a disease in which the central feature is impaired control over the use of the addictive substance," he began to parrot the explanation that this court has frequently heard from tobacco industry witnesses. 

"More people who have quit smoking than those who current smoke. Whatever addiction there is does not mean it is impossible to quit."  He soon went a step further, saying that those who quit are willing to incur the costs of doing so, and those who continue to smoke do so "because they like smoking."

His nonchalance contrasted with the last exhibit shown by the plaintiffs -- the lament of then VP-marketing Bob Bexon, who saw troubles ahead for Imperial Tobacco because the only remaining benefit to smokers was "the “drug” effect of nicotine. ...  Because they are chemically induced through nicotine smokers see these positives as reflections of their own personal weaknesses. They get them but they are not happy about it.  If our product was not addictive, we would not sell a cigarette next week in spite of these positive psychological attributes." 

Mr. Viscusi would not bite. He showed little reaction as he repeated his view that smokers understand the benefits of smoking. "It just means that this is what they enjoy. The reason they smoke is the drug effect." 

Effective communication 

Mr. Viscusi was adamant that people cannot process risk information that is expressed in numerical form. "Things like '40,000 people die from smoking.'"  The reason he gave was that people have to imagine the denominator. Giving a number out of 100 is useful he said -- but when the proportion is smaller than one-hundredth, difficulties arise.

He was similarly adamant that the concept of relative risk was inappropriate as a method to inform smokers. He defended his use of used data from a study of young American smokers that showed a high level of belief about deaths from lung cancer among smokers (six times greater than the "real risk"), while leaving out that the same youth had an even greater overestimation of the risk of death from lung cancer among non-smokers (more than sixty times the real risk). 

"The public doesn’t need to know the relative risk. They need to know the absolute probability. Relative risk is not meaningful." When Mr. Lespérance pointed out that he had stressed the importance of communicating relative risk in his arguments against plain packaging which he prepared for the CTMC (Exhibit 1680), he said it was a "different issue. I was talking about relative risk of lower or higher tar cigarettes."

Warnings don't make a difference

In a trial about cigarettes and tobacco marketing, there have been very few times when cigarette packages have actually been displayed or handled. This afternoon, Mr. Trudel showed Mr. Viscusi a few current cigarette warnings, and asked him to open a carton of cigarettes and comment on the warning he randomly selected. (A good proxy for the experience of a smoker!). 

Although he acknowledged the ways in which these warnings provided informational or sought to change the social acceptability of smoking, he refused to admit that they might reduce smoking rates. The plaintiffs did not, curiously, ask him to comment on recent Canadian studies which have measured the benefit of these new labels, i.e. Azagba et al. and Huang et al.

The Final Words

At the end of the day, Mr. Guy Pratte (JTI-Macdonald) and Mr. Simon Potter (Rothmans, Benson and Hedges) were able to ask their witness questions that allowed him the opportunity to restate their theory of warnings -- that they would have provided no benefit and would possibly have resulted in more smoking.

More health information "from a credible source would cause people to lower their risk beliefs," Mr. Viscusi obligingly repeated. The effect of such aims at deterrence would "decrease the expected cost of smoking, and thus increase smoking prevalence."

Mr. Viscusi faced two more questions on this theme:  Mr. Lespérance asked him what the result would be in a scenario where smokers actually underestimated the risks of smoking, but were then told that they were overestimated these risks. Mr. Viscusi acknowledged that if they were "convincingly told", the result would be "reduced risk beliefs and increased smoking behaviour."

Justice Riordan asked him to compare the likely impact of the specific warnings that were required by the government after 1989, and the general warnings that the industry voluntarily placed on packages in the preceding 17 years. "If you put them side by side at the same time, the specific would have more impact?" he asked. "Without question," said Mr. Viscusi.

Schools of economic thought  

Economists' capacity for debate is almost as legendary as that of lawyers. Both may have been at work today. In addition to Mr. Viscusi, there were two other trained economists at the centre of much of the day's debates.

Much earlier in this trial, Justice Riordan had revealed that he had once studied economics. (As I remember the way he said it, he also strongly deprecated any claim to expertise in the domain!). A quick search on the Library of Canada dissertation data base turfed up the thesis he completed in 1972 to qualify for a masters in economics from McGill University.

The topic was Canada's foreign aid, and what could be done to make it more efficient and more generous. A far cry from Kip Viscusi's concurrent neo-liberal formation at Harvard!.

A decade later, Mr. André Lespérance also graduated with a masters in economics. His was from the University of Montreal, and completed after he completed his law studies.

A change of topic tomorrow. Psychiatrist Dominique Bourget will testify on addiction. She is the first of three expert witnesses scheduled by the defence on this topic.

Monday, 20 January 2014

Day 200: The rational decision to smoke. Again.

"True believer" is a term I have more often heard applied to those who want to constrain the tobacco industry than to those who actively defend it. But it would be hard to deny that today's expert witness at the Montreal tobacco trials, Professor Kip Viscusi, is at the very least a "true believer" in free-market economics of the Cato Institute variety.

A long-time industry supporter 

Mr. Viscusi is well known within tobacco control circles as a result of his wide repertoire of positions against measures to reduce smoking. He was, for example, an early proponent of the idea that smoking provided society with a death benefit, as smokers died before they could collect their pensions. He has described smoking bans as an over-reaction. He once quipped that "People are no more addicted to cigarettes than they are to lawyers or the opera."

He has defended the industry in the court of public opinion, and also in courts of law. "Ten to fifteen" trials, he said today, which seemed a rather imprecise number for an economist trying to make an impression about the exactitude of his responses. These court appearances included the landmark U.S. Department of Justice proceedings before Justice Gladys Kessler

He seems a self-confident witness. He is tall, and holds himself taller. He does not pull his punches. He is not shy to denounce those whose views rival his own. (Paul Slovic's methods were described as as "trickery" and a “thoroughly dishonest survey approach.”)

But a relative newcomer to the Quebec

Economists, as the saying goes, can supply on demand. Mr. Viscusi might have been an obvious person for the companies to bring into this trial, but he was a late addition to their list of expert witnesses.

It was only as the plaintiffs neared the end of their "proof" last March 6 that Justice Riordan agreed to the companies' request for two additional expert reports on warnings.  Mr. Viscusi was the choice of JTI-Macdonald and Rothmans, Benson and Hedges. Mr. Stephen Young, who was chosen by Imperial Tobacco, will testify in March.

This is not, however, Mr. Viscusi's first appearance in a Quebec Court. He was part of Loto Quebec's defence against claims from compulsive gamblers that it had not provided warnings on its video terminals. (Exhibit 40495.1).

The voire dire

Mr. Viscusi's career success takes several pages to summarize: his 39 page curriculum vitae (Exhibit 40493) is only slightly shorter than his expert report (Exhibit 40494).

Over the past four decades, he has occupied senior positions at several prominent American universities: Vanderbilt (where he is currently "University Distinguished Professor of Law, Economics, and Management"), Duke University, Northwestern University, the University of Chicago, as well as his alma mater, Harvard University.

He has published two dozen books, and over 300 academic articles. His advice has been sought from such diverse organizations as the Environmental Protection Agency, the tobacco industry and (...sigh...) Health Canada.

These and other accomplishments were swiftly highlighted by JTI-Macdonald counsel, Guy Pratte, before he asked Justice Riordan to qualify Mr. Viscusi as "an expert on how people make decisions on risky and uncertain situations, and as to the role and sufficiency of information including warnings to consumers when making the decision to smoke." 

The plaintiffs did not contest this qualification, but they did use their opportunity to comment on his eligibility to put some framing around the testimony that would follow. Mr. André Lespérance showed that the report just filed in this trial was strongly rooted in earlier (1988) work done for lawfirms defending U.S. tobacco companies, and that the studies he uses were originally put in place by those legal teams. (Exhibit 1678)

Mr. Lespérance also suggested to Justice Riordan that Mr. Viscusi's report went well beyond the scope originally set for his appearance and that this was a manoeuvre intended to preclude the plaintiffs' rebuttal. On cue, Simon Potter acknowledged that the defence teams would ask that the rebuttal report prepared by Professor Paul Slovic should not be receivable.

"The Role of Warnings and Other Health Information in Smoking Decisions in Canada" 

Although the ideas are so outside conventional thinking that even a neutral observer might find them hard to accept, Mr. Viscusi's expert report (Exhibit 40494) is easy to read and his elaboration today was easy to follow.
Kip Viscusi says the true risks of smoking
are lower than people believe them to be. 

Smoking is not as dangerous as people think

"Peoples' risk beliefs substantially exceed scientists estimates of what these risks actually are." 

Mr. Viscusi has repeated surveys on smokers' perceptions of risk, and the results of these have   convinced him that the true health consequences of smoking are far below those that are believed by consumers. By extrapolating  from previous surveys, he believes this has been the case in Canada and the United States since at least the late 1960s.

Smokers make a rational decision to smoke.

People make the decision to smoke "with rational decision making of the usual economic fashion, in which costs and benefits are weighed against each other." Even if people "don’t sit down and calculate these probabilities" they "do respond in a sensible, reasonable way to risk."  It is not necessary to have all the information in order to make the same decision that would result if all the information were available.

Those who smoke have beliefs that smoking is less harmful than do non-smokers, which accounts for the fact that they are more likely to weigh the benefits of smoking as higher than the risks.

Young people are even more likely to exaggerate the risks

Mr. Viscusi said that young people were even more likely to think that smoking was harmful than older people. They have all the information they need to make a rational choice: it is only because "not everyone at the age or 11 is making a smart decision"  that governments put age bans into effect.

Earlier, bigger or better warnings would not have reduce smoking

"Consumers have had adequate information – both concerning particular diseases or particular incidence rates or constituents of smoke – to assist them in making rational smoking decisions." 

There would have been no reduction in tobacco use if health warnings had been put on packages sooner, or had been more detailed: "Nobody would be deterred who had not already been deterred by their beliefs." 

To the contrary, more accurate information about the risks of smoking would lead to more smokers, as it would result in smokers reducing their beliefs in the harms of smoking (by bringing them down to a more accurate but lower level).

He found proof of this in the historic smoking rates in Canada. If warnings had an effect, the smooth and steady decline would have had "discontinuous jumps" when warnings were introduced in the 1970s, or when modified in the late 1980s, early 1990s and again in 2000. (He did not explain why smoking rates did not rise at such times, consistent with his theory.)

Had warnings been effective at reducing smoking,
an effect would have shown on prevalence
data, says Mr. Viscusi.
Modern-day graphic warnings do not provide information content, but are more aligned with efforts to stigmatize smoking. "I think the overall intent is to decrease the social acceptability of smoking by increasing the disgust that people experience when they look at a package of cigarettes."

Toxic constituent labelling not useful

Information on toxic constituents would make no difference to smokers' behaviour, he said, as several levels of information were required before someone could work through the health consequences of any particular dose of every compound.  "There is no reason to believe that anyone would make a sensible judgement (from constituent labels)" 

Besides, the simple presence of carcinogens does not mean that a substance is harmful: "Scientists have said there are several dozen carcinogens in a cup of coffee – but coffee does not pose a risk." Who knew?

Insincere smokers

The fact that people report regretting their smoking behaviour does not mean that they were not making a rational choice at the moment they started to smoke said Mr. Viscusi.

He likened it to having bought a lottery ticket, and then regretting having done so when not winning the lottery. "A large percentage will have an adverse effect. and you would expect that they will regret that they were unlucky in terms of a health outcome." 

He cast doubt on reports of smokers' desire to quit, attributing survey results to insincere responses. Smokers, he said, have "learned to deflect criticism about their smoking by saying 'sure I should quit - just get off my back!' "  He pointed to the tendency of smokers who say they want to quit to drop out of cessation programs as evidence that they "don’t mean what they say."

In the end, Mr. Pratte did not need long with this witness. By mid-afternoon, after about 3 hours of questions on his report, Mr. Pratte announced that he had no further questions.

The plaintiff's cross-examination, which Mr. Lespérance started this afternoon, will finish tomorrow.

Mr. Viscusi's testimony will end on Tuesday. The last two days of the week will be taken up with a presentation by psychiatrist Dominique Bourget.